ABSTRACT

However, additional factors enter when the stakes are high. Most of us would be willing to pay up to the expected value of $2.50 for a lottery ticket giving us equal chances of winning $10.00 or losing $5.00. On the other hand, most of us would not be willing to pay as much as $25,000 for a lottery ticket with equal chances of win­ ning $100,000 or losing $50,000 even though $25,000 is the expected value of this lottery. This is because a few $50,000 losses will leave most of us without the re­ sources to continue. We cannot #/play the averages'' over a series of decisions where the stakes are this large, and thus consider­ ations of long-run average returns are less relevant to our decision making. (A vicepresident of a Fortune 500 company once commented to me, "Most of the decisions we analyze are for a few million dollars. It is adequate to use expected value for these." Whether this is true or not depends on your asset position.)

A decision maker's attitude toward risk taking is addressed in decision analysis us­ ing the concept of the certainty or certain equivalent, which is the certain amount that is equally preferred to an uncertain al­ ternative. If certainty equivalents are known for the alternatives in a decision, it is easy to find the most preferred alterna­ tive: It is the one with the highest (lowest) certainty equivalent if we are considering profit (cost). Someone who prefers to re­ ceive the expected value of an uncertain alternative for certain rather than the un­

certain alternative is called risk averse. Certainty equivalents for such a person can be determined using a utility function u(x). This function is defined in such a way that alternatives can be ranked on the ba­ sis of their expected utilities, and hence the certainty equivalent CE for an uncertain al­ ternative is determined by u{CE) = E[u(x)] where E[u(x)] is the expectation of the util­ ity for the uncertain situation. Further de­ tails on basic decision analysis are given in Clemen [1990], McNamee and Celona [1990], and Samson [1988]. Related topics are covered by Watson and Buede [1987], and von Winterfeldt and Edwards [1986]. Model Formulation

Decision trees are well-known tools for modeling decision problems under uncer­ tainty. Their use is illustrated by an actual application [Crawford, Huntzinger, and Kirkwood 1978]. An electric utility is plan­ ning a high-voltage transmission line across its service area. The general charac­ teristics of the transmission line have been selected, but the specific conductor size is still to be determined. The possible con­ ductors differ in both construction and op­ erating costs, and these costs are uncertain. The primary component of the operating cost is the cost of power lost due to heat­ ing of the conductor. For a small conduc­ tor, this loss is relatively large while for a large conductor it is smaller. Conversely, the construction cost of a small conductor is lower than that of a large conductor. The cost of the lost power is uncertain be­ cause the utility company's power genera­ tion plants use oil, and its price can vary over time. A sequential alternative is avail­ able that hedges against the uncertainties; the transmission towers can be prebuilt so

that they could hold a larger conductor than that actually installed. Then, if the price of oil turns out to be high, a larger conductor can be installed later without building new towers.