ABSTRACT

The social and economic model that emerged out of the Tiananmen crisis was profoundly different from that contemplated on the eve of Tiananmen. China made a firm transition to a high-input, high-investment, high-growth model of development. The broad but vague social consensus in favor of political and economic reforms that underlay the Tiananmen protests crumbled, while the economy boomed and some people became much better off. In the post-Tiananmen period a strong economic logic and a strong political logic coincided to produce a policy regime that was remarkably consistent and strongly self-replicating. The political crisis of June 1989 was the catalyst for a shift in the overall pattern

of Chinese economic transition. In both political and economic terms, the crisis gave urgency and legitimacy among the ruling elite to a model of concentrated power wielded more effectively. This led, on the one hand, to a regime more capable of mobilising resources for economic development. On the other hand, it resolved the ongoing discussions about ownership and hierarchy in a way that strengthened the alliance between politics and business, and integrated economic and monetary considerations into the fabric of the political hierarchy. These changes, in turn, led to a harsher and more elite-dominated form of state capitalism. For better and for worse, they also paved the way for the explosive phase of economic growth that followed from 1992 through September 2008. In and of itself, the Tiananmen crisis did not have a large impact on the Chinese

economy. Economic growth dropped sharply in the wake of the crisis (1989-90), but as Figure 10.1 shows, the economy bounced back quickly and even made up for lost time during the over-heated years of 1992-93. When the crisis is juxtaposed with China’s recurrent economic cycles (Figure 10.2), it is easy to see that the economic cycle was one of the causes of the crisis, but it is not easy to see the crisis having any effect on the pattern of economic instability. Figure 10.2 shows inflation rates as a measure of cyclical imbalance: the

Tiananmen crisis was clearly related to inflation, since it broke out after a socially destabilising peak in inflation. But the crisis didn’t immediately cause any particular change in the dynamics of the economy. Quite the contrary, there were surges in

inflation before Tiananmen, and there was one after Tiananmen, in 1993-95. If there was any clear change in macroeconomic regime, it came later, after 1996. In simple economic terms, Tiananmen was not a particularly important event. And yet, Tiananmen stands at the watershed between two different approaches

to economic transition and two different policy regimes. Tiananmen may not have been the watershed, but it certainly was located on the watershed. It is widely recognised that in many crucial dimensions, the 1980s in China were different from

the 1990s. The 1990s policy regime emerged with unmistakable clarity only a few years after the Tiananmen crisis, in 1993-94. But since it took several years for the political dynamics unleashed by Tiananmen to coalesce into a new economic policy regime, it is clear that the Tiananmen crisis was one of the most important events pushing the policy-making equilibrium from one stable state to another. What, then, is the relationship between Tiananmen and the shift in policy-making stance between the 1980s and the 1990s? The fundamental difference between the two periods is that in the 1980s, before

Tiananmen, China’s leaders were willing to subordinate other national interests to the quest for a viable economic reform model, and thus a better economy and society. After Tiananmen, while reformers still pursued a vision of a transformed economy, that vision was linked to, and often subordinated to, strengthened, stabilised, and more effective government power. The most direct measure of the difference is the provision of public goods and growth-oriented public investment. In the 1980s, this was low and declining, while in the 1990s it was high and rising. The low public goods regime of the 1980s had the advantage of purchasing ‘space’ for economic reform and freeing up resources for new organisational forms. After Tiananmen, a steadily accelerating drive for a more capable state led to a large increase in growth-oriented public investment and other public goods. In order to mobilise the resources required for these purposes, China’s leaders sacrificed important opportunities. They closed off alternative paths to reform, imposing a uniformity on policy-making choices and processes that has been, on occasion, suffocating. They ushered in a harsher, less transparent, and less ‘harmonious’ society, marked by strengthened Communist Party dominance of public property and decision making. The Tiananmen debacle deprived Chinese society of precious flexibility and

adaptability. While the crisis and its immediate aftermath were primarily political, it is important to stress that it had economic roots and consequences as well. The reform model of the 1980s would inevitably have changed and developed in the 1990s, but the particular form of the transformation was due largely to the post-Tiananmen dynamics of leadership. The first half of this paper examines the economic policy frameworks that prevailed pre-Tiananmen, and reviews the road to crisis. The second half of the paper examines the ways in which the interplay between politics and economics shaped the specific character of the post-Tiananmen regime.